National Academies Press: OpenBook

Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology (2000)

Chapter: 2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers

« Previous: 1 Background
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

CHAPTER 2

MODELS OF THE DEMAND FOR DOCTORAL SCIENTISTS AND ENGINEERS: HISTORY AND PROBLEMS

It is important to the nation that there be an adequate number of scientists and engineers. Industries that rely on scientific and technological research and development are increasingly important in both the global and the American economies. If there are too few scientists and engineers, the economy and its competitive position, both now and in the future, are put at risk. An adequate supply of doctoral scientists and engineers is also important to the nation 's colleges and universities, since these institutions train both graduate students and undergraduates and carry out university research.

Conversely, if too many people trained as scientists and engineers cannot find work related to their training, costs also result to both the scientists and engineers, and to the federal government, state governments, and universities that have subsidized the many years of education that cannot be used appropriately. In the late 1980s, predictions that shortages of doctorates would emerge in the 1990s appeared not only in the technical literature (Bowen and Sosa, 1989; NSF, 1989), but also in the media (Sovern, 1989). Young people who went to graduate school at that time and expected a welcoming job market when they received their degrees were, in many cases, sorely disappointed.

A simple illustration of the way that economists analyze the costs of shortages or surpluses is shown in the four boxes in Figure 2-1.

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

FIGURE 2-1 The social and individual costs of shortage and surplus.

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
This page in the original is blank.
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

The need to anticipate future demand for doctoral scientists and engineers, and to adjust factors that affect the supply to meet the demand, has encouraged the construction of forecasting models. Yet, as Johnson (1998) pointed out in his workshop paper, forecasting these markets beyond the very short term is extraordinarily difficult:

The future paths of levels of employment and wages in professional labor markets depend on the paths of at least ten exogenous variables. . . . Two or three of these exogenous variables, dealing primarily with the age structure of the population, can be predicted quite well for twenty or more years into the future. Other important exogenous variables, like the distribution of preferences of future college students for scientific versus other careers and future technological changes that might affect the demand for scientific personnel are inherently unpredictable. Further, there are important substantive issues involving, among other things, the heterogeneity of labor input within scientific fields and the substitution among groups of inputs with different quality/qualifications. These factors could drastically affect market forecasts and are not satisfactorily understood.

Even apparently predictable demographic change can become unpredictable if immigration increases.

Essentially, good forecasts require a well-specified model that correctly reflects behavior, is based on good data as well as careful forecasts of variables determined outside the model, and is produced by parties with no vested interest in actions taken in response to the forecast. Although past models, which were exhaustively reviewed in Leslie and Oaxaca (1993), often satisfied

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

one of these requirements,1 few have been formulated to reflect the interaction of wages, quantities, and quality, let alone what the committee called the “neglected margins” of interchangability of workers across fields, by degree level, quality, or nationality.

What happens to forecasts when models leave things out? Put simply, they can mislead. For example, the NSF models of the late 1980s did not anticipate a deep economic recession and its effect on state and federal education and R&D budgets. Moreover, they did not anticipate the end of the Cold War and its effect on defense spending, which translated into fewer jobs for scientists and engineers. They failed to anticipate the impact of legislation that abolished mandatory retirement, thereby postponing (but not eliminating) the expected retirement of doctoral faculty who had been hired in the late 1960s and early 1970s to teach baby boom children. All of these unanticipated exogenous events worked to dampen the demographically based forecasts of an increase in demand for doctoral scientists and engineers. In addition, the models failed to account for the market mechanisms that operate to bring supply and demand into balance: wage adjustments, immigration, transfer of workers across fields, and adjustments in qualifications. The difference between the NSF forecast of the number of jobs that would be available for new Ph.D.s and the actual number of new Ph.D.s placed in science and engineering jobs is shown in Figure 2-2.

This incorrect forecast resulted from unanticipated changes in the economic environment, exacerbated by the model's neglect of market adjustment mechanisms. As Johnson points out, it is beyond the capacity of a long-term market forecasting model to

1  

In particular, good demographic data and forecasts exist, as well as long time series on levels, numbers, and fields of degrees. A number of models have forecast supply and demand for scientists and engineers based on demographic variables and industrial demand based on input/output models of the U.S. economy. These models typically do not include wages and are rarely disaggregated by field.

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

FIGURE 2-2 The NSF/Atkinson forecast of supply of new Ph.D. scientists and engineers in the early 1990s and what actually happened.

anticipate all the changes that can affect demand and supply. However, if regularly updated models had been available that took into account recent events and market adjustment mechanisms, and communicated the true limits of forecast accuracy, then forecast errors would have been smaller and less surprising. Such models could have provided an earlier warning that the market outlook would not be as rosy as the analysts of the late 1980s anticipated. Instead, policymakers were surprised by the increase in the numbers of new Ph.D.s who did not have definite job commitments upon graduation and by the rapid growth in the pool of postdoctoral students, especially in the biological sciences. In response, the National Science Board asked the National Research Council to study the question of how to “reshape” graduate education to

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

improve the chances that new Ph.D.s find appropriate employment outside of academia (NAS, 1993). At the same time, Massey and Goldman (1995) constructed a detailed, field-disaggregated simulation model that forecast considerable oversupply in most science and engineering fields. Their report pointed to the demand for graduate students driven by research funding as an important explanation of why production of new Ph.D.s in science and engineering exceeded academic demand. However, wages and other market adjustment mechanisms were also missing from the Massy-Goldman model.

Much of the discussion that followed the Johnson paper focused on how models might be improved. Areas for improvement fell into three broad categories:

  • Data. Good data exist on Ph.D.s and especially on Ph.D.s in academia. Data on career paths of Ph.D.s in industry (or the classifications that would permit characterization of career paths) are lacking, as are sample sizes large enough to permit study of subpopulations in fine fields (e.g., bioinformatics). Since Ph.D. data are collected for individuals, consistency with data collected by occupations is difficult to achieve. Wage data (but not data on total compensation) by occupation are available, but not by different degree levels. Data are collected for international students who receive degrees from U.S. universities, but retention rates are difficult to determine. Data on immigrants who enter the United States after earning their Ph.D. have been collected only recently. The unavailability of data makes it difficult to model the mobility of scientists and engineers in response to changing market conditions. Finally, very little data allow for the measurement of changes of quality.

  • Model specification. Most models to date have been “gap” models that project demand and supply separately. These models neglect wage adjustments and other market mechanisms that tend to modify demand and supply and bring them into

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×

balance. Gap models thus describe structural conditions prior to the operation of these mechanisms or describe a world in which these mechanisms are believed to be ineffective. Better models would estimate demand and supply simultaneously and incorporate behavioral parameters so that changes in demand could, over time, feed back to supply and vice versa.

  • Omitted variables. Most models leave out immigration (in part because good data are lacking) and workers in science with nonscience degrees. Barnow (1998) noted in his paper that for bachelor's degree holders, at least, these flows can be substantial. For those with a bachelor's degree in computer science, 53.5 percent take a job outside computer science, while only one-third of those with computer science jobs received their degree in that field. These flows may be less prevalent in markets for Ph.D.s, but are likely to become more important during periods of increased demand for particular types of workers. A current example is the field of bioinformatics.

Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 15
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 16
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 17
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 18
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 19
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 20
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 21
Suggested Citation:"2 Models of Demand for Doctoral Scientists and Engineers." National Research Council. 2000. Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9865.
×
Page 22
Next: 3 Objectives and Approaches of Forecasting Models »
Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology Get This Book
×
 Forecasting Demand and Supply of Doctoral Scientists and Engineers: Report of a Workshop on Methodology
Buy Paperback | $39.00 Buy Ebook | $31.99
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

This report is the summary of a workshop conducted by the National Research Council in order to learn from both forecast makers and forecast users about improvements that can be made in understanding the markets for doctoral scientists and engineers. The workshop commissioned papers examined (1) the history and problems with models of demand and supply for scientists and engineers, (2) objectives and approaches to forecasting models, (3) margins of adjustment that have been neglected in models, especially substitution and quality, (4) the presentation of uncertainty, and (5) whether these forecasts of supply and demand are worthwhile, given all their shortcomings. The focus of the report was to provide guidance to the NSF and to scholars in this area on how models and the forecasts derived from them might be improved, and what role NSF should play in their improvement. In addition, the report examined issues of reporting forecasts to policymakers.

READ FREE ONLINE

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!